The Historical Evidence and Future Perspectives
Political Economy of Making and Taking from Reserve Currency
Jamaluddin Ahmed FCA PhD
Is the former President of the Institute of Chartered
Accountants of Bangladesh and the former General Secretary of the Bangladesh
Economic Association. He is currently the Chairman of Emerging Credit Rating
Limited.
Scholarly work on the national currency used in
international transactions distinguishes two views. One, familiar to
economists, emphasizes pecuniary motives. Safety, liquidity, network effects,
trade links and financial connections explain why some currencies are used
disproportionally as a medium of exchange, store of value and unit of account
by governments and private entities engaged in cross-border transactions.
Scholars refer this as the “Mercury hypothesis (according to ancient Roman
religion-Mercury was the god of commerce.” Another view, due principally to
political economists and applied mainly to the choice of reserve currency or
currencies, emphasizes strategic, diplomatic and military power. Political
economists view on the choice reserve currency or currencies, emphasizes
strategic, diplomatic, and military power, called Mercury. In so far as a
country has such power, governments of other countries may see it as in their
geopolitical interest to conduct the majority of their international transactions
using its currency. That leading power will in turn possess political leverage
with which to encourage the practice. International currency choice is from
Mars, in other words, rather than Mercury.
The “Mars hypothesis,” when added to the intellectual
portfolio of economists, may help to explain some otherwise perplexing aspects
of the currency composition of international reserves. International relations
scholars have looked at specific country cases, such as Spiro (1999) on the
dollar holdings of countries in the Middle-East, or Zimmermann (2011) on those
of West Germany in the period between 1950 and 1971.
There is much speculation today as to when the USD will
cease to be world’s reserve currency, of course, the US itself is hastening its
currency replacement through colonial rules, applying various techniques like
sanctions and trade wars. History provides evidence of reserve currency build
up period for Portugal 80 years (1450-1530), Spain 110 years (1530-1640),
Netherlands 80 years (1640-1720), France 95 years ((1720-1815), Britain 105
years (1815-1920) and the USA 110 years (1920-2030 estimated). By time line
from 1450-2030 Portugal can be cited as the first colonial power enjoying
currency hegemony which shifted from one to the other with change of hegemony
through war or other means. The USA ranked the as the 6th nation that took the
currency hegemony from Britain in 1920. In most cases changing currency
hegemony power were ended through war. The winner country’s currency took over
from the defeated nations and their currency took position of reserve currency.
The world economy requires some kind of internationally acceptable money,
otherwise the nations would be reduced to crude barter, limiting gains from
cross-border trade, investment, etc. From the economic point a single currency
might be appropriate to reduce transaction cost although the socio-political
economy does not permit in reality in all cases. The benefits of reserve
currency stressed by the economists include transaction costs, familiar gains
of international seigniorage. The political scientists include leverage and
reputation, risk of undue currency appreciation. The exorbitant privilege
enjoyed by the issuer of reserve currency which potentially is significant
distributional consequences. Cross border use of dominant currency can loosen
constraints of payments on domestic monetary and fiscal policy which is easier
for policy makers to pursue public spending objectives and external discipline
is relaxed.
Between 1860-1914, nearly 60 percent of world trade was
dominated in sterling although the UK accounted 30 percent. More recently when
dollar ruled 45 percent of international debt securities in dollar (end 2008),
86 percent of all foreign exchange transactions (2007) 66 countries being
dollar as anchor currency (2008), for many countries 70-80 percent of trade is
denominated in dollars, and most commodities are priced in dollars and dollar
still rules shadow world of crime and illicit transactions. In some ways one
could argue that private sector actions are indeed the deep determinants of
reserve currency status. Countries exhibit a certain ambivalence about their
reserve currencies because there are both benefits and costs associated with
reserve currency status. A country’s exporters, importers, borrowers, and
lenders are able to deal in their own currency rather than foreign currencies.
Thus, the transaction costs of obtaining another currency and the psychological
costs of having to move or convert from domestic to foreign currencies are
lowered and eliminated.
Having one’s currency as the reserve currency tends to
confer power and prestige in the global financial crises the USA or rather Fed,
supplied countercyclical liquidity to Europe and several emerging markets. Parity
by virtue of its reserve currency status, the Fed could use essentially its
balance sheet to help the world. This conferred prestige, and had the USA
wanted to, it could have exploited this source of power. Britain’s gradual loss
of key currency status was simultaneous with gradual political and military
pre-eminence as noted the quote from Harold Wilson. History provides
interesting examples of the reserve currency status by the US for achieving
noneconomic and economic objectives. The
ability to finance current account deficit more easily can lead to
irresponsible government and private sector behavior thereby contributing to
financial instability. The US experience in the recent global financial crisis
is a case in point, the argument being that the large current account
deficits-steaming in part from reserve currency status to a large capital
inflows and cheap easy money, which combined lax regulations led to reckless
behavior and sowed the seed for crisis. The reserve currency status and cheaper
financing it afforded, may have been the rope that allowed the USA to hang
itself.
Looking at the evidence for the demand for dollar from
private international sources, it appears that dollar not only started gaining
in ascendency in early 1920’s but also retained that status in the inter-war
years. In the pre-WW-1 nearly all issuance was in sterling but after the War an
overwhelming share was in dollars. This situation helped the US as the premier
reserve currency was considerably less than 60-plus years which was
congenitally believed closer to 5-10 years from 1919 to the mid-to-late 1920’s
but in reality, the dollar hegemony is continuing days in 2023. But the earlier
situation, if applied to current based on the index of economic dominance for
China surpassed that of USA after 2010.This can be considered as a theoretical
time line for the Chinese currency possibly overtaking the dollar after 2020
would be similar to, or even slightly greater than that between the USA and the
UK in mid-1920’s when dollar eclipsed sterling. Or which may delay transition
beyond 10 years suggested by history on the ground of non-democratic country
(China) can inspire the basic trust in rule of law that might be necessary for
spreading internationalization of currency. The key issue to note that trade is
a significant determinant of reserve currency status combined with China’s
growing trade dominance portend strongly for the renminbi. It is likely that
renminbi internationalization will be increasing rapidly. Historical experience
of the other transition-from dominance to demise of sterling is also considered
instructive on the other hand, the handover is difficult for the USA for
reasons of history, namely inheritance of the sterling area from era of empire.
This inheritance become difficult to eliminate because of the weakness of UK
economy-also the USA and UK are allies and there was consensus and concerted
efforts by governments to minimize cost of transition to the UK and
internationally.
The current environment is quite different between the USA
and China which seems to be less cooperative between the two to manage the
transition of reserve currency dominance. Before the eyebrows go up at the
magnitude and timing implied by either of the scenarios, one must be careful about
their interpretation. Many of policy changes will be needed to occur before the
fundamentals can prevail. The visible role for the renminbi as a reserve
currency may be still some ways off as it remains in convertible, restrictions
on the use of renminbi for capital account transactions, easy buy of Chinese
assts for foreigners and limited access to foreign assets by the Chinese
citizens. PBOC cannot use the renminbi to intervene in foreign exchange
markets. The heart of the problem that China’s current growth strategy is
heavily reliant on export which is fostered by competitive, undervalued
exchange rate, a closed capital account in limiting the local currency by
foreigners and for international transactions. The prerequisite for the use of
the renminbi as international reserve currency yet to market must free first
become more transparent, banks must be commercialized, supervision and
regulations must be strengthened, monetary and fiscal policy must be sound and
stable, and exchange rate more flexible. China must first move away from a
growth model where bank lending and pegged exchange rate have been central
pillars. In short, there are many reasons to believe that China is far away
from attaining major reserve currency status. Although the rise of dollar and
its eclipsing of sterling as the primary reserve currency was quicker than
expected and it would have been even quicker had politics and history no
intervened.
Regarding benefits and costs for the issuer of dominant
currency needs a comprehensive analysis must be an exercise of political
economy taking account of both economic and political dimensions. Benefits
stressed by economists include a cluster of favorable impacts at the
macroeconomic, subsumed under rubric of transaction costs at the aggregate
level and the familiar gains of international seigniorage and macroeconomic
flexibility. The political scientists add two effects are more overtly
political in nature-leverage and reputation, external constraints, policy
responsibility and misconceptions.
Differentiation of Currencies. That a hierarchy has always
tended to exist among the world’s moneys, forming what is called a Currency
Pyramid, has long been understood by students of monetary history. Today, as it
happens, there is really only one Top Currency, the U.S. dollar, which for all
its tribulations still dominates for most cross-border uses and in most regions
(Cohen 2009). Not even the gale-force winds of the recent global financial
crisis could topple America’s greenback from its perch at the peak of the
Currency Pyramid, though debate about its future continues, in the name of
Patrician currencies, people’s currency, Elite Currency play a critical
difference between the several medium-of exchange and unit-of-account roles, on
the one hand, and the two store-of-value roles on the other. Use of a currency
in foreign-exchange trading, trade invoicing, or for official intervention
purposes will almost certainly generate some measure of benefits at the
microeconomic level—denomination rents or reduced transactions costs of various
kinds. Leverage through the financial-market role is not impossible, of course.
Consider the case of Panama, which back in 1988 found itself in a grim
political dispute with the United States. Coercion via private financial
markets worked. Top Currencies or even Patrician Currencies are bound to enjoy
more political leverage than Elite Currencies. For for any government
contemplating internationalization of its currency, it is critical to keep the
entire range of potential benefits and costs. It it is also critical to keep
all the possible roles of an international currency in mind, each with its own
mix of gains and losses. If the issuer’s objective is strictly economic gain,
it is not really necessary to aspire to what we call Patrician Currency or Top
Currency status. On balance, the biggest economic benefits are associated with
just a limited range of roles—most importantly, the roles in trade invoicing
and financial markets. A country with limited ambitions, Elite Currency status
may be enough. The country that wants more—a money that will pay political and
perhaps even security dividends—strategy must be correspondingly more
ambitious. It is not necessary to give up current-account surpluses in order to
promote an international currency. Both history and logic suggest that
internationalization can be attained via intermediation on capital account
alone. The factor of time must be taken into account—the possibility that
initial gains might, in time, be offset by losses. The challenge for policy
makers is to frame strategy from the start to put off that day of reckoning for
as long as possible.
In the past two hundred years of human history, only two
nations enjoyed monetary hegemony, Great Britain and the United States, whose
money was the world’s dominant currency for medium of exchange, unit of account
and store of value. Possessing monetary hegemony gives the issuer of that
currency both economic and political gains. Many experts agree that the United
States defeated Great Britain as the top currency issuer status and established
its own monetary hegemony right after WWII. The dollar’s share in world reserve
currencies dropped to around 20% in 1933. Therefore, consensus can be reached
that the United States finally secured the dollar’s uncontested leadership
among international currencies at the end of the Second World War in 1945.
During the years following 1914, the United States came across the first golden
opportunity in the history of its monetary expansion. Because of the huge cost
of the war, the British Empire was not able to maintain the gold standard any
longer. The U.S. stayed out of the war towards the end of the war and benefited
from the sharp increase of exports to the warring states in Europe. The dollar
was the only currency to remain convertible into gold at a fixed price in the
1920s. Compared to the devaluation of the pound, the dollar began to emerge as
a major international currency; its use in international trade and finance
widened increasingly. Because of these reasons, for the first time in history,
the dollar overtook the pound as the main reserve currency in 1924. Robert
Triffin, a Belgium-born economist at Harvard University, in his 1947 report to
the Fed. He pointed out an intrinsic design flaw of the Bretton Woods system,
which was later known as the ‘Triffin Dilemma’, in his popular book Gold and
Dollar Crisis. In plain words, the Triffin Dilemma could be explained as: “if
the United States stopped running balance of payments deficits, the
international community would lose its largest source of additions to reserves.
The resulting shortage of liquidity could pull the world
economy into a contractionary spiral, leading to instability. If U.S. deficits
continued, a steady stream of dollars would continue to fuel world economic
growth. However, excessive U.S. deficits (dollar glut) would erode confidence
in the value of the U.S. dollar. Without confidence in the dollar, it would no
longer be accepted as the world’s reserve currency. The fixed exchange rate
system could break down, leading to instability (IMF, 2001, ‘The Dollar Glut’
in Money Matters: An IMF Exhibit—The Importance of Global Cooperation.
Triffin’s prophecy finally became reality. On August 15, 1971, U.S. President
Richard Nixon imposed a 90-day wage and price freeze, a 10 percent import
surcharge, and, most importantly, “closed the gold window”, ending
convertibility between US dollars and gold. A new page of monetary history was
turned. The world entered into a new era of fiat money which was backed by
nothing. When Paul Volker chaired the Fed in 1979, he began to deal with the
problem of high inflation caused by a persistent over-issuing of dollars.
Finally, the dollar started to be strong and its share in foreign exchange reserves
tended to be stable, thanks to Volker’s successful move to squeeze inflation.
The strong dollar weakened the competitiveness of American products; therefore,
in the middle of the 1980s, the United States successfully pressured its main
allies, West Germany and Japan, to appreciate their currencies against the U.S.
dollar by signing the Plaza Accord and the Louvre Accord. The collapse of the
Soviet Union and its ruble sphere provided the U.S. dollar with a whole new
world full of opportunities.
Although it only costs a few cents for the U.S. government
to print a $100 bill, other countries have to provide added value in the form
of goods or services in order to receive $100 dollars. Approximately $500
billion of U.S. currency circulates outside the United States which foreigners
ac- quired, not because their governments printed the dollars but because they
had had to provide the United States with $500 billion of actual goods and
services. This privileged position of
the dollar is not intrinsic nor inevitable but is rather a reflection of U.S.
domination and conversely, international trust in U.S. stewardship of the
dollar and the dollar-based system. Even with the closure of the gold link, the
dollar did not become a normal currency like all the others but rather,
retained its unique role as a world currency. Nonetheless, economists cautioned
that the overpriced dollar will sooner or later have to decline to a more
normal level. The crucial question is whether this will become a soft landing
or a crash landing.
Despite U.S. trade deficits and budget deficits throughout
the 1980s and onward, the dollar perversely maintained its top dog status. In
the 1980s, the dollar had no rival. Not so now. Despite economic troubles in
Greece and the Euro zone and the 2015 economic slowdown in China, things are
different today. The U.S. budget deficit, which ballooned because of tax cuts
and increased war spending, continues without solution in sight. Even in 2003,
Alan Greenspan had warned, far more urgent than tax cuts . . . was the need to
address the threat posed by the soaring new deficits. At the same time, the
combined GDP of the United States, the European Union and China together
constitute almost 60 percent of global GDP. Hence it is not surprising that there
are currently three major currencies in the world: the dollar, the Euro, and
the yuan.The focus on the currency war between the dollar and the yuan (rather
than the euro) for several reasons. First, unlike Western European countries,
China is a rival, not an ally of the United States. Second, China is a rising
global power with global ambitions, political, economic, and monetary. Third,
China has by word and deed taken steps to dethrone the dollar.
PBOC acquisition of dollars resulted in even more dollar exposure
for China. Once the PBOC held those newly acquired dollars, it also needed to
invest these dollar reserves (Morrison & Labonte, 2009) and given its
traditionally conservative orientation, it preferred to invest in highly liquid
securities issued by the U.S. Treasury. Consequently, China possessed a massive
quantity of U.S. Treasury obligations, which was estimated by some sources as
early as 2011 as $950 billion U.S. dollars.
Implication of Reserve Currencies for Competitiveness: From
the perspective of the three basic functions of money, medium of exchange, unit
of account, and store of value (Greco 2001), the monetary hegemon usually owns
a national currency which is the main medium of exchange of international
trade, the unit of account for most important goods worldwide, and store of
value for most other states. About sixty-four percent of the world’s official
foreign exchange reserves are currently held in U.S. dollars; roughly 88% of
daily foreign exchange trades involve U.S. dollars. Oil, gold and other
important goods are denominated in U.S. dollars. The international use of the
dollar brings the United States remarkable economic benefits. The Benefits of
an International Currency include, Seigniorage, Inflation tax, Cheap credit,
and Macroeconomic flexibility. Dollar Hegemony creates U.S. Privilege, Others’
Problem. John Connally, the U.S. Secretary of the Treasury, once told his
European counterparts that the dollar is our currency, but their problem.
Monetary Imperialism and Dollar Hegemony under the Breton Woods system gold and
dollars were both reserve assets in foreign central banks and the dollar’s
value was pegged to gold, thus giving foreign holders of the paper money firm
confidence in its value. The U.S. deficits continued to inflate, confidence in
the dollar’s value collapsed; private investors and central banks made a dollar
run at the end of the 1960s, which finally led to President Nixon’s decision to
stop the convertibility of dollar into gold in 1971. The monetary hegemony so far,
the United States had established was a sophisticated and complicated mechanism
centering on the Treasury bill standard. Central banks, IMF, and the World Bank
become the vehicles of this mechanism. All the rest of the world relies on U.S.
credit-creating power to develop their economies. Their dollar holdings
devalued gradually, but there was no alternative way out of this dead-locked
dollar circulation. With everyone clamoring for dollars, all the US had to do
was print fiat dollars and other countries would accept them in payment for
their exports. These dollars then flowed back into the US to be invested in
Treasury Bonds and similar instruments, offsetting the outflow. The U.S.
continued to run a large budget and balance of payment deficits in order to
finance its military race with the Soviet Union. More and more dollars were
piled up in the central banks of European countries and Japan. By persuading
Japan and European allies into the Plaza Accord and Louvre Accord, the United
States was able to devalue the dollar significantly in the 1980s against the
Japanese yen and Deutsche mark. Petrodollar Recycling, the Hidden Hand of
Dollar Hegemony, the U.S. designer of dollar hegemony had already put this
scenario in their consideration and plugged this vulnerability by linking the
dollar to oil. How could the linkage keep this dollar mechanism from
collapsing. No one would doubt the importance of oil, as it is “not just the
most important commodity traded internationally. It is the key industrial
mineral, without which no modern economy works. The dollar hegemony has been
one of the pillars of the American hegemony and probably is more important than
the other pillar, military dominance. In the cold war era, the dollar’s reserve
currency status served the U.S. military power by incessantly transporting
resources to the latter. The military power more and more plays a role of the
guardian of the money. This potential factor poses a threat to the operation of
the dollar hegemony mechanism, the gigantic military machine might start, thus
shifting the American hegemony from the ‘benign hegemony’ into a ‘dangerous
hegemony’.
The costs and benefits to the United States in a Normal
Year, the estimated net benefit from reserve currency status to be about $40
billion to $70 billion to US GDP, or 0.3 to 0.5 percent of GDP (Mckinsey Global
Institute 2009). More precisely, the United States obtains a small net benefit
from reserve currency status of 0.3–0.5 percent of GDP in a normal year. The costs and benefits of being a reserve
currency have been estimated to (+40 to +70 i.e .3% to 0.5% of US GDP). The
first class of benefit is from seigniorage income. The income generated by the
US Federal Reserve from the reserve currency status of the United States is an
estimated $10 billion. This revenue results from the ability of the United
States to receive an effectively interest-free loan on the currency it issues
that is held by nonresidents. Indeed, about half of the physical US notes and
coins—around $400 billion—are held overseas. The second class of benefit is the
cost of capital advantage obtained by borrowers in the United States as a
consequence of foreign demand for dollar assets. United States has been able to
generate an investment income surplus of a few percentage points of GDP even
with a significantly negative net financial-asset position (of about $2
trillion over the past fewyears. Reserve currency status has some sharp
distributional consequences routed from distribution of costs and benefits.
Broader economic analysis of currency hegemony status indicate possible
expression of these costs and benefits in terms of the overall impact on GDP
and employment in the normal year and crisis years. Mckinsey Global Institute
(2009) calculated that the net financial benefit of $40 billion to $70 billion
from reserve currency status converts into an overall GDP effect of $115
billion to $185 billion, or 0.9 to 1.4 percent of GDP. In a crisis year, using
the same approach, MGI (2009) estimate
that the net financial benefit converts into an overall GDP benefit of $15
billion to $75 billion, or 0.1 to 0.5 percent of GDP.
Is Dollar Dominance in Doubt. The dollar has been the global currency of
choice for nearly a century, but in light of recent U.S.-led financial
sanctions, some wonder whether that status will endure. Apart from Europe, where the euro dominates,
the majority of global trade is invoiced in dollars. The Fed estimates that
foreign investors held nearly $1 trillion in cash at the end of the first
quarter of 2021, roughly half of all U.S. notes in circulation. Central banks
around the world hold about 59 percent of their foreign currency reserves in
dollars. Much of these reserves are held as dollar-denomi- nated debt—that is,
U.S. Treasuries—rather than currency. About a third of all U.S. debt was held
abroad as of 2021, and a little over 60 percent of debt issued by non-U.S.
companies in a foreign currency was denominated in dollars. The world runs on
the U.S. dollar.
The widespread adoption of the dollar as a global currency
has long been thought of as a source of “exorbitant privilege” for the United
States, a term coined in the 1960s by France’s then Finance Minister Valéry
Giscard d’Estaing. Having a large share of trade invoiced in dollars protects
U.S. exporters and importers from exchange rate risk.
The dollar wasn’t the first currency to attain global reach,
though. In the 16th century, the Spanish silver dollar rose to prominence
through Spain’s colonial expansion. In the 17th century, Dutch florins and
bills issued by the Bank of Amsterdam became the currency of choice. By the
18th century, the pound sterling of the British Empire had become dominant—a
position it would maintain into the 20th century. Each of these global
currencies emerged organically without coordination as in Bretton Woods.
In fact, the dollar had already begun to compete with the
British pound by the mid-1920s, years before Bretton Woods solidified its
place. Economists have different theories about which of these functions is
most important for explaining a currency’s rise, but First Deputy Managing
Director of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) Gita Gopinath and Harvard
University professor and former Fed Governor Jeremy Stein argue that they are
all interconnected and reinforcing. If a currency becomes a global unit of
accounts through its use in trade invoicing, that increases the demand to hold
that currency to conduct trade, which bolsters its position as a global store
of value. Similarly, if there is a lot of global demand to hold a currency as a
store of value, that reduces the cost of borrowing in that currency and makes
it attractive for traders in other countries to price exports in that currency
to access that cheap funding market. Does the dollar’s widespread use abroad
confer an “exorbitant privilege” upon the United States as Giscard d’Estaing
claimed. Most economists agree that it has its benefits, though not many would
say they qualify as exorbitant. The law of supply and demand implies that
higher global demand for dollar-denominated Treasuries means the United States
can attract buyers at lower interest rates, allowing it to borrow more cheaply.
But in practice, this advantage appears slight.